testata inforMARE
Cerca
27 de julio de 2024 - Año XXVIII
Periódico independiente sobre economía y política de transporte
07:42 GMT+2
LinnkedInTwitterFacebook
FORUM de lo shipping y
de la logística


Special Interest Group on Maritime Transport and Ports
a member of the WCTR Society

INTERNATIONAL WORKSHOP
Genoa - June 8-10, 2000



On the Economic Impact of Ports: Local vs. National Costs and Benefits


Marco Benacchio
Università di Genova
(benacchi@economia.unige.it)

Claudio Ferrari
Università di Genova
(ferrari@economia.unige.it)

    Hercules E. Haralambides
Erasmus University Rotterdam
(haralambides@few.eur.nl)

Enrico Musso
Università di Genova
(musso@economia.unige.it)

Abstract:

It is nowadays widely accepted that the positive economic impact of ports tends to move away from a local environment (the earlier 'port city') to a much wider and often international one, including the consignors/consignees. It is thus the purpose of this paper to take a fresh look at the current changes in a port's production function, based on a territorial cost-benefit analysis, i.e. taking into account that:

  • The port industry is no longer a labour intensive one: direct employment is decreasing, while some port-related activities tend to move to inland locations;
  • The port industry is becoming more capital deepening, but given the functioning of international capital markets, the relevant payback does not necessarily stay in full within the port region;
  • Due to horizontal and vertical integration strategies, international groups often own firms which run terminals and port activities. Quite often, port impacts on the local economy are no longer among the location selection criteria of holdings, corporations and administrative departments, who often lack managerial and leadership functions;
  • Port development requires increasingly more space (a local factor) but land allocated to port activities seems to be paid less than its opportunity cost;
  • On the other hand, ports still remain important from a national perspective: they generate taxes and duties and they often constitute growth poles for national industries (e.g. manufacturing, transport, logistics) and services;
  • Finally, the costs suffered by local economies are getting higher in terms of land consumption, coast waste, environmental problems and traffic congestion.

The existence of a disequilibrium in the territorial distribution of ports wealth is thus quite evident. For this purpose Port Impact Studies are powerful tools for assessing port impact, although there is an open debate on their main goals, on the different methodological approaches and on their role in port planning.

Finally the paper attempts to formulate some suggestions for a sustainable and efficient European port system, focusing on the role of Port Authorities, investment policies, and on the meaningful involvement of local communities in deciding the "quantum" of port development.



1. Introduction: the rationale of the concept of port impact

There is a quite evident difference between the economic concepts of output (the technical result of a production process) and that of input payback (the remuneration to the factors used in the production). The case for ports can be considered as a classical production process where land, capital, firm and labor inputs (e.g. location, space, infrastructure, superstructures, facilities, human resources, management and organizational skills) are combined in order to obtain a certain level of output (throughput).

The point is that there is a general continuous interest on ports' results, while the issue of ports input payback seems to be perceived, if not less important, at least finally referable to the traffic of the port as a direct consequence.

Ports are, in fact, internationally characterized in terms of figures mainly by their annual throughput. Each year major research institutes give the up-to-date figures of world ports traffic (TEU, tons) mainly focusing on (i) their shifts (upwards/downwards) in ranking, (ii) changes in the commodity mix (e.g. the increase in containerized traffic, the decrease in liquid bulk, etc.) and (iii) future forecasts. Anyway, when an effort is made in order to measure a phenomenon, implicitly there is also a not neutral slant in such approach. This emphasis on ports' throughputs seems to cover just one side of the medal.

What do really mean "high traffic" data?

We can say that a port that is increasing its throughput is first of all a port that is "good" for the ship and the cargo (are the shipowners, in fact, who choose the port according to their port selection criteria and shippers' demand). By the way all the efforts to evaluate port performance based on different indexes (tariffs, transit time, reliability) are always referred to the port users, and not to wealth production and distribution.

Therefore high traffic means "only" that a port is more effective than other, or that it is more strategically located close to important hinterlands and/or maritime routes. Anyway it doesn't mean as a result that the port is creating "value" to remunerate inputs.

Thus for successful ports we can think at the advantages and gains collected by port users (namely multimodal transport operators, carriers, agents, shipbrokers stevedores and traders) who extract a big share of the economic rent (wealth) produced by ports, which evermore rarely stops in the port region.

Therefore we can surely assert that ports throughput is not a correct, unique and exhaustive way for evaluating port real "performance". By doing so, the risk of a misunderstanding between the user function (the utility provided by the port for the ship and the cargo) and the production and distribution function (the inputs required for achieve that level of output, and their payback) could come about.

The paper aims at analyzing the impact of ports for local economies, and its territorial distribution from a local environment towards a global "borderless" economy, considering ports economic impact as the "source" of inputs payback. The need for a particular awareness of port impact and its evolution over time is due to two main issues:

  • The fact that nowadays there is no "automatic" relation between the above functions. The remarkable growth in seaborne traffic, in fact, doesn't mean that port economies are getting wealthier. Although is quite difficult to evaluate the impact of ports, the simple trend of traffic data, moreover in containerisation, is, in fact, getting less and less significant.
  • The fact that the link between ports and port-based economies is changing towards a weakening both in the previous ties and in the economic significance.

The paper is organized as follows. Next section (§2) will briefly analyze the importance of assessing port impact on regional economies. In §3 a survey on main causes for changing impact of ports (from an economic, territorial, environmental and social point of view) is presented. An overview of different frameworks of analysis for evaluating the real positive and negative impact of ports on local economies - with focus on the aims, methodologies, results and correct use of such studies is given - is given in §4. Finally the potential disequilibrium in ports impact (namely between a local and a wider level) is analyzed, stressing the importance of carrying the analysis beyond the local level (§5), and some open points for a sustainable port development are suggested (§6).



2. The economic vs. social trade off: the importance of estimating port impact

The proliferation in the last thirty years of Port (economic) Impact Studies (PIS), despite numerous controversies regarding the strength of these kind of studies, is an indisputable objective fact that, ultimately, proves their relevance.

National and local governments, Port Authorities and port business communities, in fact, always stress the point that the development of ports could be a key factor in the economic development (and/or redevelopment) of local economies. Moreover ports play an important role from a national perspective due to the fact that they generate taxes and duties and they often constitute growth poles for national industries (e.g. manufacturing, transport, logistics) and services, improving their competitiveness.

This emphasis on ports benefits can be considered as the driving force for a sound economic justification of expansionary goals for ports activities (typically capital and land intensive investments).

Although not formally stated in statutes, port management of public ports, in fact, could be implicitly characterized by a double aim:

  • make the port attractive to users, providing a competitive supply of services for carriers and shippers (micro-economic or entrepreneurial aim);
  • raising the welfare of its citizens, enhancing social welfare in terms of income, employment, living environment, security and other aspects (macro-economic or social aim).

Despite the even existing relations between the different goals, a clear trade-off is stated: while on one hand strategies of growth and development improve income and employment, on the other may oppose other "social" goals (e.g. the need for a clean environment, for a high quality of life, for new housing development).

And the outlined trade off is getting more and more difficult to solve, i.e. taking into account some current dynamics:

  • Due to the fact that many ports are close to the full capacity, as the volume expands external diseconomies of scale, caused by congestion and lack of space, worsen the living conditions (especially for ports located in a urban context);
  • The relation between port throughput and income and employment for port economy is weakening;
  • Fierce competition between ports is increasing and borders between traditional hinterlands are fading.

As a consequence of this schematized conflict, the expansion of the port industry should be considered, from a neutral perspective, as ex post equilibrium between positive and negative impacts of ports. Extremely simplifying, in fact, the higher is the positive impact of ports on local economies, the higher the level of port expansion that would solve the trade off equilibrium, which maximizes the local utility.

Thus, only an accurate qualitative and quantitative estimation of ports positive and negative impacts, focusing also on the implicit risks as a result of spatially concentrated costs and widely distributed benefits, can provide an important tool in the policy makers decision process regarding ports development.

There seems to be a lack of convergence on the topic: different, and sometimes opposite thoughts, concerning the role of ports for modern economies, give rise to a hot debate.

Without approaching the matter of how structuring an efficient PIS, Goss (1990) suggests at least four clear reasons for which port expansion or improvement is likely to be an inefficient tool of economic development strategy:

  • Port benefits are likely to "leak" to users in inland locations;
  • Assisting and investing public money in a port will probably mean assisting foreign exporters, some of whom will be able to compete more effectively with home producers;
  • Any public assistance to a port is likely to lead to higher local taxes (local share of infrastructure financing), running the risk to make the area less attractive to residents and possible businesses too;
  • Since the aggregate demand for labour within any given economy is determined by macroeconomics factors, ports are competing among themselves for a share of a reasonably fixed level of business (e.g. the expansion of a port belonging to a range could also be at the expense of lost trade in other regional or national ports belonging to the same range).

Even if some of the outlined points have to be considered in perspective of the current context of globalization and liberalization of the markets leading to higher competitive environment and increasing of spatial interrelations and volumes of cargo traffic (also as a consequence of the improvement of the Hub and Spoke system), Goss' argumentation still remains quite effective.

Moreover another important element has to be taken into account: most of the literature deals with the problem of port economic impact from a general perspective while it is quite evident that several local/national features can affect the analysis.

Gripaios-Gripaios (1995) and Gripaios (1999), for example, draw similar conclusions for UK ports; they provide empirical evidence suggesting that often the existing and potential role of ports in the regional development process is nowadays exaggerated.

On the other hand, looking for example at the Netherlands, NEI (1996) and Bossche (1997), emphasize, even though raising problems of sustainability of port development, the economic significance of the port of Rotterdam for local and, mainly, national economy.

The topic is evidently complex and it is worth to deeper analyze both the emerging changes in ports impact and the methodological approach in conducting a port impact study.



3. Ports changing role (and its potential consequence on impact): some economic and spatial evidence

It is nowadays widely accepted that the positive economic impact of ports tends to move away from a local environment (the earlier 'port city') to a much wider and often international one, including the consignors/consignees.

From an overall perspective, globalization and deregulation set the ground for currents economic developments in which economic frontiers tend to fade and competition tends to intensify. Deregulation also allows business companies to re-organize their production systems internationally and to capitalize on advantages of different countries and regions.

For a long time the presence of a port meant not only traffic and transport activities, but also a wide range of economic activities, ranging from industries using mainly raw materials imported by sea and whose land transportation costs would have been too high, to those producing goods to be exported by sea and/or those whose optimal location was where the break of bulk took place. Nowadays, many of these industries, no longer technologically restricted to port areas, and suffering from the relative scarcity and/or high prices of space and other inputs, have moved to regions where these inputs are available at better conditions.

Besides, technological progress in transportation (lower costs) has transformed port services market from a quasi-monopoly, where the distance from other ports "protected" each market area, to a more and more competitive market.

In this new scenario the "captive market" situation has been overthrown, and port users are more and more extracting the economic rent produced by the ports, leaving to ports production inputs an even small payback. The growing horizontal and vertical integrations involving terminal operators represent both an oligopolistic response, aiming at achieving economies of scale (horizontal integration) and the attempt of transport operators to "take over" the port and its added value (vertical integration).

Finally, innovations related to the port node have been labour saving and capital intensive, as well as - which can be considered almost unique - land intensive (namely in containerised traffic). Besides the dramatic change in benefits and costs related to the port, new and different costs for the local community must be considered, like growing levels of congestion and pollution or the loss of a large amount of public resources (the coastal space).

Greater location indifference and diseconomies of congestion have allowed production activities to move away from ports. Since this coincides with an organizational upheaval of transport cycle and a reduction in land transport costs, this caused the growth of inter-modal inland terminals, which developed scale and concentration economies, and polarized traffic and induced activities. As a result, new spatial economic patterns arose, built around the new foci and routes of the transport cycle. With evident and deep consequences on ports and economic systems of port regions (Musso, 1996).

Thus, relations between the port and its local economy get weaker. Traffic flows increase, but port operations decrease, become of lesser importance, and require less manpower. Ports no longer give place to inter-industrial linkage, so that income multiplier effects not only are less relevant, but they usually spread over industries and economies even quite far from the port. The real big risk is that more and more commodities just pass through the port without stopping and/or without inducing economies activities (the port as a simple transit point), employment and added value (Vigarie', 1991).

Port services show a decreasing payback of labour and an increasing return on capital investment. While the former is located within the local economy, the latter, namely as a consequence of above mentioned horizontal and vertical integration, seldom comes either from the local economy or even from the country itself (given the functioning of international capital markets, the relevant payback does not necessarily stay in full within the port region).

This means that the economic impact of the port tends to spread more and more over the entire area of port customers (and often also internationally), while space consumption and negative externalities increase and remain spatially concentrated in the local system. This situation potentially brings about major socio-economic conflicts.

In summary, ports' records growth in throughput has not led to a corresponding increase in the number of jobs or in added value (sometimes also for all the transport and logistic functions). Therefore growing investments in port infrastructures and technologies are leading to an ever-widening gap between, on one hand, the regional use of the resources of territory, natural potentials and tax money and, on the other hand, the regional effects on employment and added value.

In the outlined scenario, costs and benefits deriving from the port should be carefully assessed, as well as their territorial impact and economic actors taking advantage from it. Namely, it is becoming ever more important using techniques for accurately measuring positive effects of the port on the local economy. These effects are largely related to the direct and indirect employment impact within the area, since other inputs are increasingly of external or international origin (firms and capital), or do not attract a sufficient payback (land's rents).

This is relevant also from an institutional and financing point of view, which will be reconsidered in the last section. In the past ports were perceived as social capital and it was the state that developed and financed ports infrastructures because of their capacity of generating employment and other indirect positive effects on the local and regional economy. But nowadays that ports are no longer the milestone in the structure of employment for the inhabitants of the port city, who are the real beneficiaries of new, subsidized infrastructures needed to maintain ports competitive? These sound doubts are leading to a different idea behind port investments, perceived as an economic capital, till some extreme positions that argue that ports should be developed and exploited as purely economic units, where public sector could not be always the prime mover (but, in a different perspective, see Suykens, 1986).



4. Methodological approaches in Port Impact Studies

For their being "critically" important there has been a series of economic articles discussing and analyzing problems and potentials of PIS: Waters (1977), Chang (1978), Davis (1983), Yochum-Agarwal (1987, 1988), Warf-Cox (1989), DeSalvo-Fuller (1994, 1995), Gripaios-Gripaios (1995), Verbeke-Debisschop (1996), Castro-Millan (1998), Gripaios (1999), Musso-Benacchio-Ferrari (1999). Port Authorities usually invest on port impact research too. As an example, the US Maritime Administration and the New York and New Jersey Port Authority, in the late seventies, developed, a famous regional port economic impact kit, based on a special form of using input-output tables, which has been updated on several occasions and which was flexible enough to adapt to the caractheristics of small and medium-size US ports (U.S. Maritime Administration, 1979 and 1985).

4.1 Aims of PIS and the choice of economic explanatory variables

The basic aim of PIS is to show the whole of the net economic benefits for local (surrounding) communities to be associated with the existence and operation of a port. The defined general aim of PIS could be composed of different sub-goals, each of them can affect the choice of the proper methodology:

1) Facilitate the understanding of the (qualitative and quantitative) relationships that exist between the port and the regional economy;

2) Measure (also overtime) the regional economic impact caused by the presence of the ports;

3) Operate as a simulation model, quantifying the economics effects derived, for example, from investments in new infrastructure.

These positive effects can be evaluated in many different ways; conventionally they are measured by the contribution of the activities of the port sector (in a broad sense) to the level reached by some economic variables such as: employment, added value, incomes, taxes and duties.

Quite often analyses are concentrated on employment terms considered as the most satisfactory proxi of the main economic positive effects for the local system. On the other side one can argue that the added value created by the port is the best variable for assessing the role of ports as catalysts for the creation of economic wealth.

In principle it could be correct, because the concept of added value is the most comprehensive measure of the actual wealth produced by ports. It is quite evident that ports who achieve to establish industrial and logistic linkages are able to produce (and potentially extract at a local level) a wider economic rent from direct and indirect port activities.

However some remarks can be outlined on the use of the concept of added value.

First of all employment is a clear (even if rough) indicator of the payback of a typical local input (labor), while added value, which could be a more powerful estimator, refers to the wealth produced and induced by the port without providing details on its distribution. For instance, what is the share of added value that goes in taxation (local and national)? Moreover if an input such as space were free, the added value of ports would be higher, but the local impact would be lower. Therefore added value figures are useful in providing a better knowledge of ports impact jointly and not alternatively to employment figures (the ratio "added value per employee" is a good measure of the economic significance of the additional port functions).

Secondly it is an estimator whose measurement is usually more subjectively biased than the employment figures. Substantial differences can be observed as regards the definition of the value-added concept. More specifically, inter-port comparisons reveal differences in defining, calculating and determining a weighing rule for converting nominal tons into intrinsic cargo handling or value tons (Charlier, 1996). Haezendonck et al. (2000) mention at least four different weighing rules within a single range, such as the Hamburg - Le Havre range, even if, in general terms, the value added concept always aims to assess the contribution of port activities to a nation's Gross Domestic Product.

Thirdly, as well as for port-related employment, it is not clear if (and in what way) the volume and the traffic structure of ports matter in value added creation (while they are chosen as the independent explanatory variable). Moreover if value added is computed from Input-Output regional (or national) matrixes, the same advantages and drawbacks seeable for employment can be outlined.

Finally, there is no reason, due to the globalization of the economic processes and firms' ownership, to support the evidence that the higher added value produced by logistic ports as Rotterdam and Antwerp surely stop in the port region. In fact the current trend of a widening and cross-bordering port economic impact is confirmed also by added valued focused researches.

4.2 Definition of economic impact

Taking the employment as a proxi of the concept of ports economic impact we can distinguish:

  • primary (direct) impact: "all activities necessary for the operation and use of the port facilities"
  • secondary impact: "all the economic activities of the area of influence of the port (local community and hinterland) that economically depend on primary activities" (Castro-Millan, 1998).

It is not easy to avoid the risk of subjectivity in the definition of the economic activities involved.

Davis (1983) distinguished the direct effects as the employment from the set of activities necessary for the operation of the port and other activities related to the outgoing and incoming shipment of the goods and passengers. The precise relationship of this set of activities may vary from port to port, which shows, on one hand, their different economic orientation and, on the other, the absence of consensus as to what economic activities are truly necessary.

He splits secondary impact into two kinds of effects: indirect and induced. Indirect effects refer to all economic activities developed in the port region and dependent on the primary activities through a technical relationship, fundamentally of the buying and selling of goods and/or services. Induced effects refer to all activities that also take place in the wide port-region and that depend on the direct and indirect effects through "consumption" linkages.

The tri-partition of port economic effects can be considered a stable distinction in different studies.

Yochum-Agarwall (1987, 1988) proposed an interesting conceptual framework in which they provide general guidelines for conducting a port's economic impact analysis. The organization of an efficient search for port-related industries is based on three different linkages between the port and the region's economy.

  1. Employment in firms providing services necessary to the movement of waterborne commerce (port required industry). They provide:
    • transportation services (e.g. freight forwarding, transport of cargo by rail and road);
    • port services (e.g. terminal operations, stevedoring, vessel supply, pilotage, towage, ship repair, diving services, insurance, legal services)
  2. Employment in firms attracted to the region because of the presence of the port (port attracted industry). The availability and potential access to port facilities may well serve as a "magnet" to attract industries to sites located near a port. The economic advantage of close proximity to a port is such that port attracted firms would considering moving from a region if the port facilities were closed down. They typically fall into two categories:
    • firms that export commodities;
    • firms that import products or raw materials for assembly and distribution (e.g. steelworks, chemicals, refineries)
  3. Employment in firms that have expanded their markets (demand for their products) by exporting through the port (port induced industry). The port is a source of reduced transportation costs, which results in industry expansion. Such industries are typically located at a substantial distances from port facilities (and on the basis of a mere geographical criterion they would not be correctly identified). They are port dependent in that cost-effective access to the port affects demand for the firm's products. Such industries however could be located in the region regardless of the availability of port facilities (therefore is much more difficult to establish their degree of dependence on the port).

Quite similar is the "Dutch" functional approach to the segmentation of the economic impact of ports (Bossche van den, 1997), in which are distinguished:

  1. Direct economic effects

    Those effects are related to the "core" of the port. It concerns the actual employment (and gross added value) to be found at the - geographical - centre of the port (related to the basic activities carried out in the port).

  2. Backward linkages

    To perform their core activities, the economic actors that are comprised in the direct effect will use goods and services from subcontractors who need other subcontractors and so on. The total amount of employment connected with those subcontractors ads up the so-called backward linkages. The ratio between backward linkages and direct effects is called the backward multiplier.

  3. Forward linkages

    Without the presence of the port, those activities either would not take place, or would take place against higher operating costs, or would be located elsewhere (maybe outside the national economy). As for the previous port induced industry, it is much more difficult to measure forward linkages in an objective and transparent way (e.g. risk of overestimating for possible doublecounting).

The picture is greatly complicated by what we can call the "historical" employment impact: that is, the employment in industries that are still located in the port area because they used to be "port oriented" in the past.

Moreover all these definitions implicitly identify a fourth set of firms that are not affected at all by the presence of the port. But it is not certain whether the fourth group even exists, as it is arguable whether any sector exists that is not at all affected by the distribution of wealth originating from port activities.

This is why, finally, also preliminary approaches concerning definitions can affect results from different PIS that should never been compared a-critically.

4.3 Choice of the methodology for employment assessment

- Rough guess methods, ad hoc survey methods

It is not rare to find port impact studies not based on rigorous methodology. When the "political" aim (i.e. emphasis on the port benefits) is the real goal for generating communication among main parties involved in the decision processes leading to the allocation of public resources to seaports projects, the issue of methodological approach for a careful assessment fades into the background. Port Authorities quite often justify tailor-made solutions due to the peculiarity of the case study, but they do not provide transparency on calculations. For a critical survey on such "geographical" and ad hoc survey methods for estimating port employment and value added see, for example, Isemar (1997) and Haezendonck et al. (2000).

- Models of port demand

Following a series of empirical studies based on the port of Tampa (USA), DeSalvo and Fuller (1994, 1995) have advanced a methodological proposal which attempts to offer a simple conceptual framework to evaluate a share impact of ports. The impact depends (i) on the cargo volumes transshipped by the port and (ii) - taking into account the changes in local output due to price changes - on the price elasticity of the demand for imports and exports channeled through that port.

They showed that a reduction in both exports and imports (due to an exogenous "shock": a stop or a decreasing in port activities), will cause, besides a loss in direct employment, an increase in transportation costs. This will lead to a final result of higher sale prices of the products and a progressive reduction in the global quantity imported/exported). Moreover also internal production costs, and consequently, the sale price of the domestic products that use imported goods in their production process will boost. This, in turn, will bring down the demand of such products, which, sooner or later, and depending on the market structure, will mean a reduction in employment and output in the analyzed area.

- The economic base approach

The central aspect of the model, which implies that exports have an autonomous behavior, rests on the believe that regional income critically depends on the export sector, where the economic base multiplier is expressive of the changes income would experience in light of autonomous changes in exports.

The adoption of this model, in particular for port-impact analysis (Isemberg, 1957; Kraft, 1966), has been criticized for three main weaknesses:

  1. It considers as a non-basic (or endogenous) sector all activities related to the flows of imports;
  2. The model only provide an aggregate multiplier (a substantial increase in exports of a determined good has exactly the same multiplying effect as an equal increase in exports of a different good);
  3. The model mainly computes the induced effects without offering satisfactory assessment of the indirect effects.

- The Keynesian Income-Expenditure approach

This model, derived from the core of most macroeconomic demand models, has been suggested to calculate the secondary impacts derived from port activity. In the income-expenditure final multiplier the critical element is the marginal propensity to consume goods produced internally.

From the point of view of port economic impact studies, this approach, which has some advantages over the base-export models (it considers that imports substitution can constitute an income-generating factor), has also the disadvantage of only providing one multiplier for the computation of the induced effect, and not offering any information about the technical and/or economic interrelations that exist among different sectors.

- The Input-Output Approach

One of the most fruitful approaches to assess port economic impact is that based on an input-output analysis (Warf-Cox, 1989 and Castro-Millan, 1998). The system of producers and consumers is divided into different branches, which are defined in terms of the resources they require as inputs and what they produce as outputs. The quantities of input and output for a given time period, usually expressed in monetary terms, are entered into an input-output matrix within which one can analyze what happens within and across various sectors of an economy where growth and decline takes place and what effects various subsidies may have. In this way, the impact of the previously defined port-related sectors can be computed with a breakdown level depending on the matrix framework.

There are several reasons supporting the utility of the model. Firstly because this kind of analysis allows obtaining a multiplier for each one of the activity branches considered. Moreover, if also private consumption and households wages and salaries are considered, it permits to compute the whole sectional multipliers (including then direct, indirect and induced effects). On the other hand this method is very expensive (in terms of costs and time) and sometimes national I-O matrixes are used for a long period for regional purpose (with an evident lack in local details).

- Adjusted Location Quotients

Musso-Benacchio-Ferrari (1999) proposed (and applied to Italian ports) a technique for estimating the port's employment local impact assumed as the employment that can be ascribed to the port within the above mentioned direct,indirect and induced impact.

Employment impact is evaluated in terms of shares of employees to be ascribed to the port impact according to the estimated probability that industries are totally or partially port oriented (compensation approach). The technique basically consists of rules for estimating the importance of port in the employment of each industry. It is a mix of four different analytical tools:

  • the "control regions" technique, for the territorial definition of port economies and non-port economies (PE and NPE)
  • the location quotients analysis, for the comparison between port economies and non-port economies
  • the shift share analysis, for the attribution of the share of employees for each selected industry belonging to a port economy
  • calculus of probability, to remove the random and/or biased component from the data.

The many advantages of the proposed approach are in the sense that:

  • it avoids any discretional bias: there is no arbitrary evaluation, neither on definition of "port related" industries, nor in the share of employment attributable to the port;
  • it is relatively easy, from the point of view of time and cost, in that it does not require direct data collection but just census data: in most advanced countries there exists data available on employment, with suitable level of territorial and industrial breakdown.

By the way there are still some points open to improvement:

  • it gives rise to a strong discretion in the choice of homogeneous control regions (which ideally should be homogeneous to the PE except for the existence of the port);
  • the problem of underestimation as a result of compensations has no satisfactory solution, but can only be coped approximately;
  • the proposed technique does not join with input-output methods, neither with the wider Keynesian macro-economic inducement evaluation.

4.4 Some empirical results

In principle, comparing results obtained from different studies, different methodologies and different periods is nor easy neither correct.

A part from methodological issues, it is important to state that PIS are first of all decision supporting tools for regional planning, giving an estimation of ports inputs payback, and not a sort of model for benchmarking ports impacts in different contexts. In fact even if it were possible to compare ports positive effects computed for the same time and unbiased by methodological approaches and discretionary estimations, what would be the "added value" of such a comparison? Port direct and indirect activities have in fact a very close causal link with the historical, geographical and institutional background of the local economy, which are elements not at all (or partially) under the control of the port community. Moreover what could be considered as a higher economic impact in terms of employment or added value might be lower, compared with other ports, in terms of dues, duties and tax flows.

A comparative table of the results from different PIS is therefore here included just to provide some general elements of discussion.

Port
Year
Cargo Tons.
Employment
Comments
Rouen (FR)
1991
23 M.
14,535
Elaboration on census data (geographical criteria)
Dunkerque (FR)
1993
40 M.
20,343
Elaboration on census data (geographical criteria)
Nantes/St. Nazaire (FR)
1995
30 M.
24,265
I-O + weighed estimation
Anvers (BE)
1988
97 M.
63,500
Geographical criteria + direct survey: only direct employment
Anvers (BE)
1995
111 M.
114,440
Geographical criteria + direct survey: 56,770 (direct)
Gand (BE)
1995
21 M.
24,428
Geographical criteria + direct survey
Bruges-Zeebrugge (BE)
1995
30 M.
11,263
Geographical criteria + direct survey
Rotterdam (NL)
1995

1996

284 M.
160,500
Direct survey + I-O analysis: 63.000 (direct) + 35.000 (backward) + 62.500 (forward on the national level)
Genova (IT)
1991
42 M.
35,390
Adjusted Location Quotients
Genova (IT)
1996
47 M.
35,771
Adjusted Location Quotients
Santander (ES)
1993
4,5 M.
28,935
Empirical survey + I-O analysis
London (UK)
1996
53 M.
28,337
Employment in a-priori defined port related activities: sea and coastal water transportation, cargo handling, storage, warehousing, other transportation activities and other transportation agencies.
Southampton (UK)
1996
34 M.
4,832
 
Liverpool (UK)
1996
31 M.
5,161
 
Plymouth (UK)
1989
2 M.
627
Survey + Estimation: direct + Indirect
New York/New Jersey (USA)
1977
61 M
227,100
I-O + survey techniques. Induced effects computed for USA
New York/New Jersey (USA)
1985
53 M.
250,800
I-O + survey techniques. Induced effects computed for USA
Hampton Roads (Virginia, USA)
1984
55 M.
45,732
Direct surveys: 12738 (p-required) + 3399 (p-attracted) + 29595 (p-induced)

Sources: Isemar, NEI, Warf-Cox, Yochum-Agarwal, Musso et al., Castro-Millan, Gripaios-Gripaios, Gripaios.


The wide range of values and approaches suggests some comments.

From a methodological point of view most of the studies, besides using sophisticated techniques, can't avoid a share of subjectivity (interviews, surveys, estimations). Moreover, the input-output matrixes used are "adapted" (regionalized) from national economy I-O matrixes, when a regional one is not available. Beside the fact that it doesn't seem to be a transparent method due to the fact that details of the "regionalising" procedures are not given, moreover this doesn't allow to take into account several local economic features.

Concerning data, it seems to be no apparent relation between the estimated impact and the total volume of ports throughput. A more accurate analysis (as performed by Warf-Cox, 1989) should distinguish between changes in cargo volumes, and changes in the commodity mix. The impact attributable in to changes in the commodity mix arise from the fact that different commodities require different handling methods, and thus different amount of labour, material and service inputs for their loading and unloading. For example a rise in the share of trade accounted for containerized traffic will decrease aggregate direct labour inputs such as stevedoring services, potentially increase indirect effects due to logistic activities performed on high value goods, increase capital investments and expenditures on items such as fuel oil, in turn indirectly altering patterns in the local economy. Within the traffic mix, the role of transshipment is generally not taken into consideration, while the effects of passengers (ferries and cruises) usually seem to be underestimated. Moreover, while all of the studies report global figures of port-related employment, few of these try to analyze the breakdown in different categories (e.g. Warf-Cox, 1989). Nevertheless it is quite evident that the structure of the induced employment (workers, professionals, engineers etc.) is an important indicator of the quality of the impact, of its added value and of the leadership functions of the port region.

Moreover, the fact that containerization and standardization of cargo and related procedures may change the role for ports from industrial/service linkage to a simple transit point, sometimes can also lead to moves of main port related premises of holdings, corporations and administrative departments towards inland locations, while executive branches still remain close to the port. This has to be seen as a high risk for the port local economy to loose important managerial and leadership functions.

Finally, the computed results are, in general, not so relevant. Moreover quite often the growth in tons does not lead to a comparable growth in terms of employment (for instance the throughput of Rotterdam grew on average 1.6% per year during the period 1987-1997, while direct and indirect impacts decreased on average 2.8% per year). In that respect the causal relationship of port and city economy has been reversed. Ports are no longer the economic engines of seaport towns, while the differentiated production and service networks of the region constitute a prerequisite for the economic benefit of the ports in term of a value added and employment oriented service center (i.e. the case of Rotterdam and Antwerp).

All the above considerations implicitly stress the point that PIS are more effective if repeated over time in order to constantly monitoring changes in the economic relationship between the port and the city.


4.5 Main criticisms to PIS and their role in economic and port planning

There are several critics moved versus port impact studies.

The "original" criticism made by Davis (1983) pointed out the lack of a thorough investigation of the degree of dependency on the ports of the various activities included in the impact component. PIS investigators, in fact, not only have to face with the obstacle of searching for firms whose business is related to the port (roughly the first task), but, once identified, they have to establish the degree of a firm's (industry's) dependence on the port (second sub-goal). Unfortunately, due to its nature, the assessment of this degree of dependence runs the risk of a very subjective estimation. When data are lacking to correct assess ports impact, there may be a strong bias, of some of the parties involved in the decision making process, to overestimate mainly indirect effects.

The second criticism of PIS has been on their practical applications in terms of either estimating period to period changes in economic impact or measuring the incremental benefits of additional port investments. Waters (1977) attributed to these lacks the drawback that PIS usually do not provide useful guidance for port planning. Chang (1978) stated that "PIS are static in that these studies measure the economic impact of port operation usually for one year only during which collected data are relevant".

The need of replications over a period of time, in order to use impact studies in a more correct and powerful way, is quite evident. The fact that, despite all the outlined remarks, PIS usually remain una tantum studies, is due on one hand to the high cost of data collection and calculation of this kind of analysis, and, on the other hand, on the short term political aim which is usually associated to PIS (promoting port expansion).

The most significant and relevant criticism made by Randall (1988) on the use of economic impact studies in the forms indicated above, is that the selection of port specific industrial categories does not reflect the true functional profile of the port. He emphasizes the natural "proactive" role of seaports and, on the basis of the current trends in cargo handling (namely capital intensification and space consumption), supports a sound justification for Port Authorities to engage in non-marine economic development (from real estate agency and development to custody of bridges and tunnels, from industrial tourism to co-ordination of community festivals). A part from the wealth effects, these non-marine functions often play an important role both in promoting the port itself and in strengthening the link between the port and the port community.

A further remark is in the sense that PIS usually fail to provide reliable guidelines in determining whether or not port facilities should be expanded (while quite often they are used exactly for this goal). The simulation role of PIS has to be carefully considered. First of all it is important that they provide to assess the likely effects of projects in terms of sustainable employment and/or added value in order to avoid overestimated unrealistic expectations (e.g. construction and maintenance effects have to be reduced by the component which is probably not very different from other projects, while economic trends which are not sustainable over time have to be removed). Secondly they should be used only to estimate a port's short run economic impact, since technology is held constant, while the structure of the port (organization, management, equipment) may change. Furthermore port economic activities are affected by international events and by institutional changes as well.

More reasonably we can summarize that PIS serve as an important tool to the community in understanding the structure of a port as well its immediate economic effects. They can provide insights for a meaningful address in port planning: from a pure supply-led transportation strategy (which sometimes leads to port overcapacity in order to compete in the market), to a more balanced incremental stepwise combination of supply-led and demand-led industrial strategy.

There is a further point that seems to be quite important and often underestimated. PIS are seldom recognized as an aid to the decision making process on the overall economic regional planning. The usual perspective of utilization, in fact, is quite "narrow": politicians and decision-makers usually look at them as the main tool for port (expansion) planning.

If the first general aim of PIS is to provide a detailed analysis of the existing relationships between the port and the regional economy, then we have to agree that their utility is wider than that of a "black box" for simulating port impact under different scenarios.

Their "added value" is to give a better knowledge of the economic framework of a port region and therefore they have to be considered as an important layer in the economic and spatial planning of the whole region. They support economic evidence (the benefits of the port) that have to be compared with costs, and then translated in options for an integrated global economic planning, and in priorities for better decisions on the economic, social and territorial development of the region (as well as other sector studies).

Only if PIS are considered as an important "cognition" estate for the local government, and their key role in port planning is correctly integrated in the overall economic planning, it could be possible to limit some of the frictions between the different players involved (port users, community groups, local business community, different government layers) enhancing cooperation and synergies (Hoyle, 1999).



5. The "local" cost-benefit analysis and the "wider" (national, supranational) context

The port economic impact (direct and indirect) has finally to be compared to the costs suffered by local economies that are getting higher in terms of land consumption, environmental problems and traffic congestion.

Schematically we can outline the main (monetary and non-monetary) costs of the port presence for the local economy as in the following:

  • The local share of investments in maritime and port infrastructures, transport infrastructures;
  • Opportunity costs of port industry inputs: capital, labor, space (coast and landscape);
  • Negative "sunk" externalities: environmental aspects (air, water, acoustic pollution), landscape decay, irrecoverable investments in facilities, traffic congestion, costs for "conciliating" the presence of the port in a urban context, the risk of hazardous material handling (chemicals, petrochemicals);
  • Eventually loss of managerial and leadership functions for local port economies that are quite no longer among the location selection criteria of holdings, corporations and administrative departments of the firms located within the port region.

Verbeke-Debisschop (1996) argue that, even when PIS correctly perform a cost-benefit analysis, they usually don't take into account "external effects and do not allow to introduce shadow prices for the valuation of specific inputs and outputs". Given that the market prices are used for the measurement of all the costs and positive effects (when they are monetary valuable), any distortion of the market from a perspective of economic efficiency will lead to a biased picture of the real effects. Due to the fact that in port production function imperfections usually affect the inputs market (e.g. for the mechanism of land allocation and pricing in ports) the risk of overestimating net port impact is substantial.

The quite evident disequilibrium between a reduced positive economic impact of ports, which tends to move away from a local environment to a much wider and often international one, and the increasing costs and negative externalities, which remain spatially concentrated in the local system, seems to have no straight solution.

A problem of territorial distribution effects in fact occurs, taking into account that:

  • labor usually comes from the local port economy and its payback stops in port region;
  • capital more rarely originates from local systems while it is quite often provided by national and international systems (and consequently its payback doesn't stop in port regions);
  • firms may be local actors, but horizontal concentration (between big stevedoring and logistic companies) and vertical integration (between shipping companies and terminal operators) tend to internationalise firms ownership;
  • port land use is usually regulated by leasing and concessions contracts but quite often land prices are a strategic tool for attracting companies and they don't reflect real value of the space;
  • the use of the fixed social capital of the local system (namely transport infrastructures) is free (free-toll roads and highways) or it pays fees sometimes lower than costs (e.g subsidisation) to economic agents who often operate on a wider territorial scale (rail, motorway operators);
  • taxes and duties are just partly earned and managed by local port systems;
  • port users who benefit from port benefits are more and more spread all over the world, while negative impacts affect mainly port regions.

The outlined impasse seems to have no straight solution: the risk is that of a "refuse tip" effect, such as ports as facilities not desirable for local communities, more and more necessary for other countries economies while more and more economically less significant for their regions (Musso, 1996).

It seems meaningful, therefore, (re)considering the dis-equilibrium between cost and benefits for the local economy within a wider comparison between global cost and benefits, including those for the hinterland. Ports, in fact, still remain very important even from a mere national perspective. They generate tax flows and duties, provide direct positive effects on Gross National Product, Balance of Payments and Balance of Trade. Wider effects are in the sense that ports constitute growth poles for national industries (e.g. manufacturing, transport, logistics) and services, act as macro-economic tools for territorial policies aiming at developing depressed areas, and provide access to international markets and foreign investments.

On the other hand national costs for ports development seem to be sum of the local negative impacts (although not directly equally suffered by all the population), with in addiction:

  • the national share of investments in maritime and port infrastructures, transport infrastructures;
  • organizational and coordinating costs between central government and local port authorities/harbour master offices;
  • human resource costs (e.g. early retirements funds for ex-dockers of pools).

Even if these costs can be considered still compensated (even if with a decreasing margin) by overall benefits, a clearly imbalance on costs and benefits distribution still arises.

Finally according to the perspective of a wider overall economic system port industry plays more and more an irreplaceable role as central links in the logistic chains of the global economy. Port users benefit from the port activities mainly in order to reduce their own production costs and increase demand of their product and services.

Providing a comparative overview of the results of five investment projects in Belgian ports, Blauwens (1993) shows, in the form of the net return per invested Belgian Franc (benefit ratio), that the benefit count is usually lower from a Belgian point of view than from an international one. In recent studies NEI (1996, 1997) has investigated the size of the forward linkages connected to the Rotterdam port activities both on a national and European scale. On the national level the direct effect brings along forwarded linkages for the 70% of the direct value added, and for the 100% of the direct employment. The cross-border relationships between the port and its users in its hinterland are even more evident. In 1997, on a basis of 24 billion Nlg of national added value generated by the port, an additional 24 billion Nlg of gross value added can be found in other countries (mainly in Germany and Norway).

Another important element has to be added to this unbalanced scenario, underlining the lack of control by port communities in the strategic planning of port development. Although port positive effects for regional economies are fading, ports are more and more under pressure due to the current high shipping lines volatility in calling at ports (Meersman et al., 1999) and the already highlighted location indifference of port related firms. This force ports (and port economies) to face potential crisis through a unconditioned supply-driven port planning leading to a structural overcapacity which worsen local conditions. Such a vicious circle may determines potential severe conflicts between local community and decision makers concerning port matters, sharpened also by the perceived lack of representation of local interests by port governance.



6. Facing the disequilibrium: some open points towards a sustainable port development

All the above considerations could be synthesized in the following points:

  • the increasing competitive environment between ports decreases single port's economic rent;
  • growing investments in new port infrastructures and technologies are leading to an ever widening gap between, on one hand, the regional use of the resources of territory, natural potential and tax money and, on the other side, the regional effects on employment an added value;
  • while benefits are generally increasing, their distribution effects are widening (towards a "borderless" economic system) and they are becoming less concentrated in the local port system;
  • the local communities are bearing the weight port industry development, and the risk of an irrecoverable overcapacity;
  • social conflicts related to port development are getting more and more important (Port Authorities, community groups, business community, national and local government).
Within such a scenario could be still realistic (and to what extent) considering ports as catalysts for regional economy growth and development?

The issue has to be carefully addressed. It is, in fact, correct to look at the economic role for ports from a global perspective taking into account at the same time regional and wider contexts. While the former perspective of ports as powerful economic tools for regional growth seems to be outdated, the mere consideration of ports as critical links in the global transport network bypasses the main problem of a correct input payback for the local system. The synthesis can be achieved in recognizing that the issue of port development it is not an unconstrained maximisation model, but, first of all a matter of (spatial and overtime) sustainability of costs and benefits.

From a local point of view the idea of port sustainability implies the improvement of the trade off between costs and benefits (first of all through a more correct payback of ports input), and the possibility that the all the actors belonging to the port community (local community in primis) can play an active role in deciding the "quantum" of the port expansion and the amount of the resources to be allocated.

Several open points can be outlined concerning different factors, about which decision makers (at local, national and European level) should argue in order to co-operate in drawing meaningful policies, and consequently actions, for a fairer distribution of port effects.

Impact assessment - The first and concrete step in such a broad topic should be the effort of adopting common conceptual frameworks and "objective" quantitative methodologies in order to assess the role of ports for economic systems in terms of (i) local impact (direct-indirect employment and territorial impact), (ii) fiscal flows and returns on investments, (iii) international effects of the ports within a global economy.

Land use and pricing - Concerning inputs of port's production function, a suitable market structure in port land use (at the same time efficient for the "supplier", i.e. the local community, and effective for the "purchaser", i.e. direct and indirect users of port services), can be considered one of the main priorities (Musso-Benacchio, 1999). Consistent rental policies have to try to link as much as possible leasing rents directly to the costs of local communities (including opportunity costs of space) not otherwise countervailed by benefits.

Port Infrastructures - New schemes for infrastructure pricing and financing have moreover to be implemented, in order also to correctly apply the user pays principle stated by the major recent policy document of European Commission (European Commission, 1997). Following this perspective an efficient decentralization of port tax systems could be considered as a first step for allowing ports (mainly in the Mediterranean area) to have more control on investment decisions.

Port networking strategies - It is not a futuristic scenario that which foresees breaking through administrative borders of single ports entering into partnership with surrounding nodes and regions (Van den Berg - Van Klink, 1997). This could lead to a more rational planning, selections and locations of port activities. Control of knowledge-intensive activities and co-ordination of partnerships with other nodes could be considered as ports core new business, allowing port regions to held leadership and control of all transportation and logistical flows and related added value activities.

Co-operation in the decision making process - Analysis of interests/conflicts, co-operation and synergies among all the players (directly and indirectly) involved in port planning (from state government to ports users) have to be actively promoted. For this reason Port Authorities have to ideally play as "chairmen" in the roundtables of the decision making process regarding port planning and development. The meaningful involvement of local communities (which sometimes are among the weaker parts of the port stakeholders community) should be considered an important target, in order also to regain a sort of legitimacy of governmental institutions (firstly Port Authorities) in territorial planning, which quite often is questioned. Since critical inputs of port's production function are supplied mainly from local systems (natural resources, labor and infrastructures), is therefore a main point that local communities take part in port decisions (although in the forms of representation).



References

Berg L. van den, Van Klink H.A. (1997), "Networking: the main strategy of the 21st century", in Gout, Haffner, Sinderen (eds.), Mainports in the 21st Century, Wolters-Noordhoff, Groningen

Blauwens G., De Brabander G., Van de Voorde E. (1993), De dynamiek van een haven, Uitgeverij Pelckmens, Kapellen.

Bossche M.A. van den (1997), "The economic importance of mainports" in Gout, Haffner, Sinderen (eds.), Mainports in the 21st Century, Wolters-Noordhoff, Groningen

Castro Villaverde J., Millan Coto P. (1998), "Port economic impact: methodologies and application to the port of Santander", International Journal of Transport Economics, Vol. XXV-2, 159-179

Chang S. (1978), "In defence of port economic impact studies", Transportation Journal, Vol. 17, 79-85

Charlier, J. (1996), "Le concept de tonnages pondérés en économie portuaire", Paper presented on 'Conférence au CIRTAI (Le Havre)'

Davis C. H. (1983), "Regional Port Impact Studies: a critique and suggested methodology", Transportation Journal, Vol. 17, 61-71

DeSalvo J., Fuller D. (1994), "Measuring the direct impacts of a port", Transportation Journal, Vol. 33, 33-42

DeSalvo J., Fuller D. (1995), "The role of price elasticities of Demand in the economic impact of a port", Review of Regional Studies, 25, 13-35

European Commission (1997), Green Paper on Port Infrastructures, COM 97-678

Goss R.O. (1990), "Economic policies and seaports. The economic functions of ports", Maritime Policy and Management, Vol. 17, 207-220

Gripaios P. (1999), "Ports and their influence on local economies - a UK perspective", The Dock & Harbour Authority Vol. 79:894, March/April 99

Gripaios P., Gripaios R. (1995), "The impact of a port on its local economy: the case of Plymouth", Maritime Policy and Management, Vol. 22, 13-23

Haezendonck E., Coeck C., Verbeke A. (2000), "The competitive position of seaports: introduction of the value added concept", International Journal of Maritime Economics, volume II, n. 2, 107-118

Haralambides, H.E. (1996), The Economic Impact of Shipping on the National Economy, International Conference on Shipping, Ports and Logistics Services: Solutions for Global Issues, IAME, Vancouver, B.C., Canada, 1-18 (methodological part of the EU 4th Framework Research Progr.: «European Economic Impact Study for the European Shipping Sector»).

HMSO (1988), The Employment effects of urban development corporations, House of Common Employment Committee, Third report, Vol. II., London

Hoyle B.S. (1990), Port cities in context: the impact of Waterfront regeneration, Transport Geography Study Group, Institute of British Geographers, University of Southampton

Hoyle B.S. (1999), "Scale and sustainability: the role of community groups in Canadian port-city waterfront change", Journal of Transport Geography, vol.7, n.1, pp.65-78

Hoyle B.S., Hilling D. (1984), Seaport systems and spatial change, London, Wiley & Sons.

Isemar (1997), La mesure de la valeur ajoutée liée aux activités portuaires, Syntese n.3, Decmber 1997

Isemberg G. (1957), Existenzgrundlagen der Stadt, Köln

Isserman A. (1990), Research design for quasi-experimental control group analysis in regional science, West Virginia University

Kraft D. (1966), Der Einflus eines Hafens auf die Wirtschaftsstruktur und dieWirtschaftskraft seiner Hafenstadt, Göttingen

Kreukels T., Wever E., eds., (1998), North Sea Ports in transition: changing tides, Van Gorcum, Assen

Lloyd's List (1999), The Dutch Maritime Cluster: A Network of Excellence, London

Meersman H., Moglia F., Van de Voorde E. (1999), "Mergers and alliances in liner shipping: what do European port authorities have to fear?", Liner Shipping: What's next?, Proceedings of the 1999 Halifax Conference, IAME.

Musso E. (1996), Città portuali: l'economia e il territorio, Franco Angeli, Milano

Musso E., Benacchio M. (1999), "Porto e territorio: un rapporto in evoluzione", Economia e Diritto del Terziario Vol.3.

Musso E., Benacchio M., Ferrari C. (1999), The economic impact of ports on local economies: a technique for employment assessment, in Dombois R., Heseler H. (eds.), Seaports under the conditions of globalization and privatization, Bremen: Universität

NEI (1996), Value added port of Rotterdam (phase 1), Rotterdam: Stichting Netherlands Economisch Instituut

NEI (1997), European forward economic linkages of the port of Rotterdam, Rotterdam

Randall J.E. (1988), "Economic development and non-marine inititiatives at American seaports", Maritime Policy and Management, Vol. 15, 225-240

Rietveld P. (1994), "Spatial economic impacts of transport infrastructure supply", Transportation Research, vol. 28A, 329-341

Suykens, F. (1986), "Ports should be efficient (even if it means that some of them are subsidized)", Maritime Policy and Management Vol. 14, 105-126.

U.S. Maritime Administration (1979), Port Economic Impact Kit, Office of Port and Intermodal Development, Washington DC

U.S. Maritime administration (1985), Port Economic Impact Kit, Recht Hausrath & Associates, Oakland Cal

Verbeke A., Debisschop K. (1996), "A Note on the Use of Port Economic Impact Studies for the Evaluation of Large Scale Port Projects", International Journal of Transport Economics; 23(3), October 1996, 247-66.

Vigarie' A. (1991), Villes portuaires et changements economiques, in: Association Internationale des Villes et Ports, 3rd International Conference on "Cities & Ports", Genova, 19-22/XI/1991

Voigh F., Witte H. (1981), "Analysis of the Growth and Structural Effects Induced by a Transportation System", in International Journal of Transport Economics, vol.VIII, n.1, pp.47-58.

Warf B., Cox J. (1989), "The changing economic impacts of the port of New York", in Maritime Policy and Management, vol.16, pp.3-11

Waters R.C. (1977), "Port economic impact studies: practice and assessment", Transportation Journal, Vol. 16, 14-182

Yochum G.R., Agarwal V.B. (1987), "Economic impact of a port on a regional economy", Growth and Change, n.2, 74-87

Yochum G.R., Agarwal V.B. (1988), "Static and changing port economic impact", Maritime Policy and Management, Vol.15, 157-171

›››Archivo
DESDE LA PRIMERA PÁGINA
Las asociaciones del sector marítimo a puerto denuncian la ausencia del MIT en las mesas en las que se decide la asignación de los recursos del RCCDE
Roma
De manera alarmante-subrayando-la falta de un desglose de los fondos a favor del Ministerio de Infraestructura y Transporte
Considerable reducción adicional en el tráfico de mercancías en el puerto de Taranto
Taranto
En el segundo trimestre de 2024, el descenso fue de -30,7%.
En el segundo trimestre de este año, el tráfico en los puertos marítimos chinos creció un 3,1% por ciento.
Pekín
Los únicos con envíos extranjeros aumentaron un 8,4% por ciento y los contenedores subieron un 7,5% por ciento.
En el segundo trimestre, los resultados económicos de Konecranes crecieron
Helsinki
Caída de pedidos en pedidos, pero superior al trimestre anterior
Ingresos trimestrales de CMA CGM creciendo gracias a nuevas adquisiciones
Ingresos trimestrales de CMA CGM creciendo gracias a nuevas adquisiciones
Marsella
Volúmenes de contenedores transportados por la flota hasta un 6,8% en el segundo trimestre
Salvini pide que los planes de estudio de las partes interesadas presiden nueve Autoridades del Sistema Portuario
Roma
Las candidaturas deberán presentarse antes del 10 de septiembre.
Otro trimestre extraordinario para Royal Caribbean Cruises
Otro trimestre extraordinario para Royal Caribbean Cruises
Miami
En el periodo abril-junio en la primera mitad de 2024, se rompieron numerosos registros.
Declive decidido en el rendimiento económico del grupo ferroviario alemán DB
Berlín
En la primera mitad del -10,2% por ciento de los bienes transportados por DB Cargo. También disminución en el rendimiento de DB Schenker
Rasmussen (BIMCO): La reducción de la actividad de demolición de los portacontenedores aumentará en el futuro
Copenhague
Mientras tanto, la flota mundial ha alcanzado nuevos récords.
Cumbres renovadas de las asociaciones de agentes marítimos y spedicers del Spezia
DSV, ingresos trimestrales crecientes pero no ganancias
Heddesheno
En el período abril-junio, aumento de los envíos aéreos y marítimos
Crecimiento del 4% semestre del tráfico de contenedores en terminales HPH Trust
Hong Kong
Ingresos del 2,6%
Órdenes de carnaval Fincantieri ser tres cruceros de 230.000 toneladas de arqueo bruto
Miami
Serán las más grandes jamás construidas por la empresa navalmecánica y las más grandes jamás realizadas en Italia.
Publicado en USA la norma que prohíbe a las compañías navieras rechazar injustificadamente las ranuras de carga
Washington
VOCC tendrá que demostrar la subsistencia de motivos razonables para negar los espacios
Nuevos registros trimestrales y semestrales de contenedores y mercancías convencionales en puertos españoles
Madrid
Se inició la construcción de la terminal trimodal del grupo MSC en la región de París
Ginebra
Se espera que en 2027 el tráfico anual alcance cinco millones de teu
No del Gobierno de Londres a una garantía estatal sobre nuevos préstamos solicitados por Harland & Wolff
Londres
"El mercado está en la mejor posición para resolver los problemas de negocios que enfrenta la compañía", dijo.
En el puerto de Nápoles, se inicia la obra de fortalecimiento de la presa foranea Duke d' Aosta.
Danés Norden compra Norwegian Norlat Shipping
Hellerup
Está especializada en el transporte marítimo de productos forestales
Meyer Werft confirma la posibilidad de aplicar la reestructuración del grupo navalmecánico
Meyer Werft confirma la posibilidad de aplicar la reestructuración del grupo navalmecánico
Papenburg
Se anunció la definición de un borrador de un plan que se espera que se complete en 2028
IBIA, el indicador de intensidad de carbono actual de la OMI penaliza el negocio de bunkerage
Londres
Presentado una propuesta para cambiar el CII antes de la próxima sesión del MEPC
COSCO Shipping Puertos, en junio nuevo registro histórico de tráfico de contenedores mensual
Hong Kong
En el período abril-junio de este año, también se registró un nuevo récord trimestral.
Ligero crecimiento trimestral y semestre del tráfico de contenedores en el puerto de Algeciras
Algeciras
Nuevas locomotoras para el transporte transalpino de SBB Cargo International
Munich de Baviera
Orden a Siemens Mobility
Nuevo récord histórico de tráfico de contenedores mensual en el puerto de Barcelona
Barcelona
También se registraron nuevos picos máximos de volúmenes en contenedores trimestrales y semestrales
Nuevo récord histórico de tráfico de contenedores mensual en el puerto de Barcelona
En el segundo trimestre, el tráfico de mercancías en el sistema portuario de Amberes-Zeegrugge creció un 4% por ciento.
En el segundo trimestre, el tráfico de mercancías en el sistema portuario de Amberes-Zeegrugge creció un 4% por ciento.
Anverso
Los contenedores fueron iguales a casi 3,4 millones de teu (+ 2%)
Puerto de Rotterdam, en recuperación del tráfico de contenedores en el segundo trimestre
Puerto de Rotterdam, en recuperación del tráfico de contenedores en el segundo trimestre
Rotterdam
En la segunda mitad del año, se espera que los volúmenes aumenten en otros segmentos del mercado.
CMA CGM concuerda con Google para aplicar inteligencia artificial a operaciones de grupo
Marsella
Entre los objetivos, aumentar la eficiencia del uso de la flota y los contenedores
Le Aziende informano
ABB completa l'acquisizione del business di routing meteorologico di DTN per la navigazione
La transazione è stata completata oggi, in seguito a un precedente annuncio di accordo con il gruppo globale di dati e analisi DTN
En el primer semestre de 2024 el tráfico de contenedores en el puerto de Los Ángeles creció un 14,4%
Los Angeles
El crecimiento de las ganancias de ABB mientras caen pedidos
Zúrich
Aumento de las confirmaciones en los sectores marítimo, portuario y químico
Asiterminal, utilizar los fondos del RCDE UE para la inversión en infraestructuras y nuevos equipos para las empresas portuarias
Asiterminal, utilizar los fondos del RCDE UE para la inversión en infraestructuras y nuevos equipos para las empresas portuarias
Roma
Los sindicatos están abandonando la deriva de confrontación en la Ccnl.
Marsa Maroc operará dos terminales en el puerto beninés de Cotonou
Casablanca
El negocio se celebrará junto con la nueva empresa público-privada Bénin Manualidades
Clerc (Maersk): Los próximos meses también se caracterizarán por una deficiencia de retención en contenedores frente a la alta demanda
Copenhague
Acuerdo en Bahréin para crear un astillero de reciclaje de astilleros
En mayo, se acentuó el declive del tráfico naval en el Canal de Suez.
En mayo, se acentuó el declive del tráfico naval en el Canal de Suez.
El Cairo
Los cruces de petroleros han disminuido un -41,5% y los de buques de otro tipo en un -59,4%.
Cognolato es el nuevo presidente de Assiterminal
Roma
Ferrari confirmó director de la asociación de terminalistas portuarios
El CIMAC ha sido acreditado con estatus consultivo en la Organización Marítima Internacional
Fráncfort del Meno
Barco de carga general detenido y sancionado por la Guardia Costera de Génova
Génova
Constatados incumplimientos graves de la legislación europea de reciclado de buques
Las renuncias de los comisarios europeos Valean y Sinkevicius en el Parlamento de la UE
Bruselas
El rebote de los ingresos registrado por OOCL continúa.
Hong Kong
En el segundo trimestre de este año, crecieron un 14,4%
Puerto de Singapur registra nuevos registros históricos de tráfico trimestral y semestral de contenedores
Singapur
Nuevos picos máximos también de graneles no petroleros
Pedidos de 2.700 millones a KSOE para la construcción de 12 15,500-teu portacontenedores
Seúl/Sejong
La Comisión de Comercio Justo autoriza al KSOE a adquirir el 35,05% del capital de STX Heavy Industries
FMC bloquea la entrada en vigor del Acuerdo de Gemini Corporation entre Maersk y Hapag-Lloyd en operaciones con los EE.UU.
Washington
Se volvería automáticamente efectivo el lunes, pero la agencia estadounidense solicitó más información.
En el primer semestre de 2024, el tráfico de mercancías en los puertos rusos cayó un -3,1% por ciento.
San Petersburgo
Productos secos en disminución de 2,7% y masa seca de -3,5%
En el puerto de Klaipeda comenzará la construcción de un nuevo terminal de cruceros
Klaipeda
Se espera que el trabajo se vaya a partir de este año
Inaugurado el nuevo puerto indio de transbordo
Inaugurado el nuevo puerto indio de transbordo
Tiruvanantapuram
El calentador de agua profunda en Vizhinjam es administrado por los puertos y la logística de Adani
En el segundo trimestre, los actos de piratería contra los buques, pero no la violencia contra la gente de mar, disminuyeron.
En el segundo trimestre, los actos de piratería contra los buques, pero no la violencia contra la gente de mar, disminuyeron.
Londres/Kuala Lumpur
Se reportaron 27 ataques en comparación con 38 en el período de abril a junio de 2023.
Suscripción del acuerdo para la renovación del Ccnl de la industria del armador
Roma
Aumento global del parámetro medio (nostrome) de 202 euros
Global Ports Holdings acepta oferta de adquisición del accionista mayoritario GIH
Londres
La propuesta incluye la eliminación de la empresa
GNV publica su propio informe comunitario 2023
Génova
Catani: Generamos anualmente impactos directos, indirectos e inducidos de 1,360 millones de dólares en la economía italiana.
Cambios aprobados en el presupuesto de previsión para 2024 de Western Ligure AdSP
Génova
OK of the Management Committee at conventions with RFI for last-mile links
Sindicatos, aprobaron la renovación de la gente de mar ' contrato y desbandada la reserva
Roma
Algunas críticas en el sector del remolque
El AdSP de Cerdeña acelera los gastos de infraestructura
Cagliari
Cerca de 60 millones de euros de sumas disponibles en exceso de 2024
Adjudicada la licitación para el nuevo pavimento de los muelles 19, 20 y 21 del Puerto de Ancona
Ancona
Parte de las actrices del ferry serán trasladadas a la zona.
Medlog (grupo MSC) se convertirá en el copropietario del nuevo puerto interior belga de Limburg
Bruselas
Asociaciones con Essers y Machielos
En el camino en el puerto de Augusta el trabajo para la realización del nuevo puesto de control fronterizo
Agosto
Se completarán en enero de 2025
En los primeros cinco meses de 2024, el tráfico de mercancías en el puerto de Nápoles creció un 5,8% por ciento mientras que en Salerno cayó un -1,0% por ciento.
Nápoles
Aprobado el DPSS de la Autoridad del Sistema Portuario del Mar Tirreno del Norte
Livorno
El instrumento establece los objetivos y las estrategias de desarrollo coordinado de los puertos del sistema
En el segundo trimestre de este año los ingresos de UPS cayeron un 1,1%
Atlanta
Beneficio neto-32,3%
Estable el volumen de negocios trimestral del grupo logístico Kuehne + Nagel
Schindellegi
En crecimiento, los ingresos generados por los envíos aéreos
Nuevo servicio de Transporte Bertani para el transporte ferroviario de automóviles entre Chignolo Po y Cassino
Milán
El 6,5% de la flota en navegación es capaz de utilizar combustibles alternativos o propulsiones
Nápoles
Trafigura se convierte en el único propietario de los petroleros de alta temperatura
Singapur
Adquirido el 50% del capital en mano en Gearbulk
Positivo el segundo trimestre de Wärstilä
Helsinki/Trieste/Roma
Crecimiento acentuado en el segmento marítimo
Lanzado un ro-pax de Bluferries
Atenas
A partir del inicio del próximo año, conectará Villa San Giovanni con Messina
Acuerdo Fincantieri-Hera para la optimización del ciclo de residuos
Bolonia/Roma
Se establecerá un nuevo co. La actividad se pondrá en marcha en el astillero de Monfalcone
ENEOS de Japón cede la flota de buques cisterna y graneleros a un nuevo participante al 80% por ciento de NYK
Japón
La venta no incluye barcos para el transporte de petróleo crudo
PROXIMAS SALIDAS
Visual Sailing List
Salida
Destinación:
- orden alfabético
- nación
- aréa geogràfica
Fondos de la UE por 765 millones de euros en la nueva línea ferroviaria-Lyon
Bruselas
Acceso también financiado al túnel de base del Brennero
Medtruck (grupo MSC), acuerdo con los sindicatos sobre el salario y los derechos
Roma
En los próximos 15 días se llamará a los trabajadores para que se pronuncien sobre el acuerdo.
Inaugurado el nuevo enlace ferroviario intermodal entre el Interpuerto de Toscana Central y el Terminal de Darsena Toscana
Césped
A la llegada en el puerto de La Spezia los medios navales para la construcción de los nuevos cruceros de muelle
El Spezia
Se utilizarán para la consolidación del fondo marino y la prefabricación y puesta de las barricas
Rhenus ha inaugurado dos plantas cerca de Bolonia y Milán.
LAUZAC
Nuevas sucursales en Castel San Pietro y Casei Gerola
En junio, el Puerto de Long Beach establece un nuevo récord de tráfico de contenedores para este mes
Long Beach
El BEI financia 90 millones del proyecto de la Darsena Europa del puerto de Livorno
Luxemburgo
Guerreros: pleno apoyo político y financiero para su realización
Acuerdo entre la AdSP del Adriático Central y la Policía Estatal para la prevención y contraste de delitos cibernéticos
Ancona
Cross (Assessopers): No detener la realización de grandes infraestructuras
Génova
Presa de Génova, Tercer Valico y la autopista de la parrilla-señala-son obras esenciales
En el primer semestre de 2024 el tráfico de contenedores en el puerto de Hong Kong cayó un -5,4%
Hong Kong
En el segundo trimestre, el descenso fue de -7.5% por ciento.
Renovado el acuerdo quinquenal entre los armadores honrados y el IMAT para la formación de las tripulaciones
Castel Volturno
Saipem ganará dos proyectos offshore en Arabia Saudita
Milán
Nuevos activos por valor de 500 millones
Se ha llevado a cabo el trabajo sobre la realización de la nueva entrada al puerto de Augusta.
Agosto
Di Sarcna: Trabajo estratégico también a la luz de la reciente transferencia de tráfico de contenedores de Catania
La fuerte demanda de contenedores se refleja en los beneficios del CIMC
Hong Kong
Registrado un aumento significativo en las ventas de caja seca
Los Servicios de Aduanas de ALS han adquirido los Servicios de Aduanas de Battaglino
Hilden
La empresa de Milán tiene 79 empleados
Aprobado el presupuesto 2023 de Interporto Campano
Nola
Confirmado Alfredo Gaetani (Presidente) y Claudio Ricci (Director Gerente)
Saipem, se compromete para actividades offshore en Azerbaiyán
Milán
En la actividad del programa en las aguas azerbaiyanas del Mar Caspio
El grupo danés SGL compra Brazilian Blu Logistics Brasil
Hvidovre
Acuerdo para adquirir todo el capital social
99,2% de los 400 millones de Fincantieri de aumento de capital suscrito a
Roma
El accionista mayoritario CDP Equity se ha suscrito a nuevas acciones por valor de 285,8 millones de euros.
El 17 de julio, la asamblea pública en Assiterminal se celebrará en Roma.
Roma
Messina (Asseswarms): con la renovación del Ccnl de la industria del armador respuestas válidas a las necesidades de los trabajadores
En la terminal de contenedores de especias iniciar las vieiras de los buques de contenedores de 21.000-teu de OOCL
El Spezia
Inaugurado la planta de suministro de energía en tierra del puerto de Valletta
Floriana/Ginebra
Cada miércoles "MSC World Europa" se conectará a la red eléctrica de la escala
PSA, medidas para mitigar la congestión en el puerto de Singapur están teniendo éxito
Singapur
En los últimos meses, ha aumentado, entre otras cosas, la necesidad de manejar contenedores varias veces.
Presentado el XII Informe Nacional sobre la Economía del Mar
Roma
El sector genera un valor añadido directo de 64.600 millones de euros.
Instalación en la obra de Ancona construcción del crucero de aluminio extra-aluminio Cuatro Temporadas I
Trieste
Fincantieri lo entregará a finales de 2025
Hapag-Lloyd anuncia los resultados preliminares del primer semestre
Hamburgo
La compañía cree que la segunda mitad de 2024 será mejor que las expectativas previas.
En mayo el tráfico de mercancías en el puerto de Ravenna disminuyó un -3,0%
Ravenna
Se espera que el mes de junio disminuya un -3,3% por ciento.
El análisis económico-financiero de Fedespedi de compañías navieras en contenedores
Milán
Colocación de la quilla del nuevo megayacht de ultra lujo destinado a Aman en el mar
Génova
Ceremonia en la obra de San Jorge de Nogaro de T. Mariotti
Danaos confirma orden en China para cinco nuevos buques portacontenedores
Atenas
Cuatro tendrán una capacidad de 9.200 teu y una de 8.258 teu
En Barcelona la primera terminal de contenedores en el Mediterráneo con muelle electrificado
Barcelona
El viernes la inauguración de la planta de suministro de energía en la costa de Hutchison
PUERTOS
Puertos italianos:
Ancona Génova Rávena
Augusta Gioia Tauro Salerno
Bari La Spezia Savona
Brindisi Liorna Taranto
Cagliari Nápoli Trapani
Carrara Palermo Trieste
Civitavecchia Piombino Venecia
Interpuertos Italianos: lista Puertos del mundo: Mapa
BANCO DE DATOS
Armadores Reparadores navales y astilleros
Expedicionarios Abastecedores de bordo
Agencias marítimas Transportistas
MEETINGS
El 17 de julio, la asamblea pública en Assiterminal se celebrará en Roma.
Roma
Messina (Asseswarms): con la renovación del Ccnl de la industria del armador respuestas válidas a las necesidades de los trabajadores
La asamblea de Assagents se celebrará en Génova el 25 de junio.
Génova
Evento titulado " Mari inquieti. Rutas y conflictos: la incognición de los traficantes "
››› Archivo
RESEÑA DE LA PRENSA
Samsung, HMM clash in US over shipping rates
(The Korea Times)
Houthis Mount Biggest Month of Attacks on Ships This Year
(Bloomberg)
››› Reseña de la Prensa Archivo
FORUM de lo shipping y
de la logística
Relazione del presidente Tomaso Cognolato
Roma, 17 luglio 2024
››› Archivo
El crecimiento de los ingresos de los taiwaneses Evergreen y Yang Ming continúa
Taipei/Keelung
YML ordena 9.100 nuevos contenedores
Inaugurado en Gioia Tauro el muelle que acogerá el polo de reparaciones navales
Alegría Tauro
Agostinelli: Este año el tráfico de contenedores en el puerto desafiará los cuatro millones de teu
El grupo chino Hengli construirá un astillero en la isla de Changxing
Dalian
Inversión del valor de 1 300 millones
SFL Corporation renueva con Maersk el alquiler de cuatro portacontenedores
Hamilton
La capacidad de los barcos será alta de 8.700 a 9.500 teu
Prysmian, registro de instalación de un cable en aguas ultraprofundas
Milán
Ensayo de instalación a -2.150 metros
El Rhenus de Alemania ha adquirido el 15% de los C Chez Vous de Francia
Holzwickede
Está especializada en la entrega de mercancías con un peso superior a 30 kilogramos
Astilleros Armon entregó el ferry de combustible dual Margarita Salas a Baleària
Dénia
Puede ser alimentado a gas natural licuado
Hermanos Cosulich ordena dos nuevos petroleros químicos
Génova
Se tomarán en entrega en el primer semestre de 2026
Fincantieri vara a Ancona el crucero Viking Vesta
Los Angeles
A mediados de 2025 se entregará a American Viking
Linaje compra el proveedor abruzzese de los depósitos frigoríficos de Eurofrigor
Amsterdam
Gestiona una estructura de celdas refrigeradas de más de 24.000 metros cuadrados en Controir
Al final la fase constructiva del puerto de Porto Torres
Cagliari
Encomendada a un panel consultivo técnico sobre la cuestión de los mayores costes de la ópera
En China, se ha establecido la quilla del nuevo ro-pax. GNV Virgo
Génova
Será el primer barco de la flota de GNV en ser alimentado por gas natural licuado
En Génova, el Día Mundial de la Navegación Ausile
Génova
El 22 de agosto, IALA asumirá el estatuto jurídico de la organización intergubernamental
SFL Corporation ordena la construcción de cinco portacontenedores de 16.800 teu
Hamilton
Compromete el valor de mil millones de dólares a New Times Shipbuilding
En 2023, Fratelli Cosulich registró un rendimiento financiero sólo superado por los registros de 2022.
Génova
OMT (Accelleron) adquiere el OMC2
Luces
La compañía fabrica inyectores de combustible de alta precisión para motores marinos, estacionarios y ferroviarios
El año pasado, el tráfico de mercancías en los puertos holandeses cayó un -7,6% por ciento.
La Haya
Reducción de volúmenes en todos los principales compartimentos merceológicos
Chantier Naval de Marsella se retrofit otros dos cruceros de AIDA Cruises
Rostock
Forman parte de la clase "Esfinge"
Genovese De Wave ha adquirido Inoxking
Génova
La compañía fabrica muebles de acero y sistemas de refrigeración para la industria marítima
La caída del tráfico de contenedores en el puerto de El Pireo continúa
Hong Kong
En general, se han aumentado los volúmenes gestionados por la red de puertos de envío COSCO.
MSC obtiene el 97.71% del capital de Gram Car Carriers
Oslo
En los próximos días la adquisición de las acciones restantes
Hapag-Lloyd reitera su propia división terminalista
Hamburgo
A Hanseatic Global Terminals hacen 20 terminales de contenedores en 11 naciones
ADNOC Logistics & Services ordena en Corea 8-10 nuevos buques de gas natural licuado
Abu Dhabi
Serán construidos por Samsung Heavy Industries y Hanwha Ocean
Kombiverkehr está alarmado por la reducción de los servicios de DB Cargo para el transporte intermodal
Fráncfort del Meno
La empresa está buscando socios alternativos
- Via Raffaele Paolucci 17r/19r - 16129 Génova - ITALIA
tel.: +39.010.2462122, fax: +39.010.2516768, e-mail
Partita iva: 03532950106
Registrazione Stampa 33/96 Tribunale di Genova
Director: Bruno Bellio
Prohibida la reproducción, total o parcial, sin el explicito consentimento del editor
Búsqueda en inforMARE Presentación
Feed RSS Espacios publicitarios

inforMARE en Pdf
Móvil